Practical endgame on issuance policy

It is quite natural to not perceive all points as fully addressed from the first response in a discussion. This often requires further back and forth.

The focus of my response was to the following statement: “If there are 100MM eth and 50% is staked that’s very different than only 50MM eth and 50% staked.” Under the current issuance policy, Ethereum is incapable of handling this scenario correctly, because the offered yield would differ since it varies with deposit size and not deposit ratio. So I explained the plan to rework our issuance policy to handle that. This has all been worked out but will be phased in over several hard forks. In essence, we will track the circulating supply and swap out D for d in the equation of the reward curve, also including the circulating supply S.

When it comes to the influence of market cap, this was described in the first paragraph of the link I provided as the start of my answer. If you could find the time to review these links, it would be very beneficial, since it takes up a lot of time answering these questions.

The contention is thus that we cannot focus too closely on market cap when specifying the reward curve.

Clearly, you consider issuance policy as an instrument for affecting transaction demand. You discuss inflation and deflation, sharing opinions on how it will affect user behavior, with quotes such as “the incentive people have to spend immediately if they otherwise get diluted”, etc.

This is however not the purpose of Ethereum’s issuance policy. We do not and shall not rely on issuance policy to affect transaction demand, but solely to affect the willingness to supply stake. Whether ETH deflates or inflates does not factor into the equation. Thus, I do not “feel the need to discourage users from transacting”, because I know that it is a fruitless endeavor. I am strictly focused on security and composition of the staking set.

There is nothing to avoid, because we do not try to influence transaction demand with issuance policy. Slight inflation implies that Ethereum is incapable of securing its network when relying on current revenue. For this reason, deflation is a healthy sign for any cryptocurrency.

An LST that provides a five times lower staking yield to its customers will have a very hard time to compete. But this is not integral to the discussion, let us move on.

The primary motivation for a reduction in issuance is the reduction in costs, leading to a welfare gain. I have linked the relevant write-up and figure on this several times, but will present it here also, if you perhaps missed it.

Two reward curves are shown in the figure, both under the present level of MEV (300k ETH/year) and the hypothetical supply curve used in the post. The supply curve indicates the amount of stake deposited D at various staking yields y. It captures the implied marginal cost of staking. What that means is that every ETH holder is positioned along the supply curve according to how high cost they assign to staking, with their required yield implying that cost. Relevant costs include hardware and other resources, upkeep, the acquisition of technical knowledge, illiquidity, trust in third parties and other factors increasing the risk premium, various opportunity costs, taxes, etc. The area above the supply curve indicates the stakers’ surplus (what they actually gain) and the area below the supply curve the costs assigned to staking (the marginal staker would not stake at a yield below the supply curve).

By maintaining the current reward curve in black, Ethereum compels users to incur higher costs than necessary for securing the network. Adopting the red cubed reward curve from the post eliminates implied costs represented by the dark blue area, thus improving welfare. These implied costs amount to around 344 000 ETH, corresponding to 859 million dollars.

The issued ETH covered for hardware expenses, taxes, reduced liquidity and risks that users would choose to sidestep under a lower yield. With the red curve, they can, and the benefits are shared by everyone (including remaining stakers), creating value for all token holders through a reduction in newly minted ETH. It may seem strange that it matters how many new ETH that are created. But imagine if every ETH was converted to 10 ETH tomorrow so that there were 1.2 billion instead of 120 million ETH in total. Then every ETH would be around 10 times less valuable. What matters is the proportion of all ETH that you hold. There is also a surplus shift from stakers to everyone from a change in issuance policy, indicated by the darker grey area. That ETH indeed previously benefited stakers, since it was taken from everyone (in the form of newly minted ETH), and then given specifically to them.

It is important to understand that the cost reduction corresponding to 859 million dollars is the yearly savings, not a one-off event. The implied cost reduction applies each year, benefiting Ethereum’s users on an ongoing basis.