Practical endgame on issuance policy

A misrepresentation or misunderstanding. The full statement is:

The topic under discussion is the welfare gain from a cost reduction for the ETH token holder. It is desirable to be able to calculate this cost reduction, and it turns out that we can simply specify the cost as the reservation yield of the stake. The SSP will pass on its costs to the delegator, who will decide to stake when accounting for the fee of the SSP. We can thus rely on the integral of the supply curve for computing the aggregate cost. This is a separate topic from how the composition of the staking set is affected by a change in issuance policy. In this case, it is certainly important who runs the validator, as addressed throughout my responses and the FAQ. Indeed, this is the reason for why a stake capping strategy should potentially be avoided in my view.

I use the term solo staker to cast a wide net. For the sake of analysis, it is not critical if we are dealing with a squad staker or a small solo staker under Orbit SSF. My perspective was outlined in my previous answer.

This is a misunderstanding of the topic being discussed in this part of the response. The topic is that the supply curve represents the cost of staking. For a better understanding, read my response to Keyneom starting here:

Also review the associated figure.

Also a misunderstanding of properties of the supply curve. Refer to my previous answer for an explanation of the topic being discussed.

  1. The supply curve will go almost vertical at a high proportion staked. Think of all the people that wish to hold ETH on hand, that will find a 0.5% staking yield too low if they need to trust a third party with their ETH, etc. Or review the cryptocurrencies that do not reach the full supply staked even at a 5-10% yield.
  2. It holds at both 2% and 2.5%, that’s the point. A 0.5% issuance rate becomes a 2% issuance yield at 30M ETH staked. The discussion in that part of the text relates to the common suggestion during the debate at that time that striving for 30M staked is too low because then Coinbase may rely on economies of scale to outcompete all other SSPs. But this could only happen under a stake cap that targets a low stake. It is not a possible scenario under a more moderate reward curve because the staking yield would still be 2%.

Perfect competition is a term in economics, and my suggestion in this part is that staking services are not perfect substitutes:

One take-away is that fees will not be driven to zero.

Thanks.

I focus on 32 ETH as a natural baseline for historical reasons. It would be particularly painful to make many 32-ETH validators unprofitable from a decentralization perspective. I focus on 1 ETH as a natural lower bound in Orbit SSF designs.

Counterarguments here.

Great link! Interesting to read thinking from the early days. A relevant section to me would be this.

They’re violating the rules they are supposed to abide by, but with 92% of all ether, who’s going to stop them? “This is important”, they say. Within minutes, a new longer chain has outpaced the fork that contains the hack, history has been rewritten, the world has collectively decided to forget those transactions.

While it is not perfectly clear if the author meant to refer to all ETH or all staked ETH, a key reason for MVI is precisely because of the fear that all ETH would be staked when some black swan event takes place. Consider the impact of a black swan event causing a chain split in this scenario. It would make it very hard for the community to come to social consensus. I’ll quote my write-up from the MVI thread that outlined this idea:

  1. …LST holders and any application or user who needs the LST to preserve its value will develop a shared destiny with both the LST and ultimately the LST issuing organization (the SSP).

  2. In the case of a mistake or misdeed, which may also take place at any mechanisms designed to regulate the organization (such as smart contracts, on-chain governance, or government regulations), Ethereum’s social layer may not have the capacity for appropriate (non) measures.

  3. It would require Ethereum to destroy a large part of itself. The affected users may prefer to reinterpret the mistake or misdeed as something entirely different. Once you become the money of Ethereum, you to some extent become the social layer.

  4. The money function is in this way a Ryanian “stratum for cartelization” that acts one layer above the various strata (e.g., MEV extraction, block-timing manipulation) that Ryan explores in his post on the risks of LSTs.

  5. We are no longer only concerning ourselves with the proportion of the staked ETH under an LST, but the proportion of the total ETH under an LST. The corrupted institution(s) correspondingly also sits one layer above the consensus mechanism, namely the social layer.

  6. It became apparent with The DAO that if the proportion of the total circulating supply affected by an outcome grows sufficiently large, then the “social layer” may waver on its commitment to the underlying intended consensus process.

  7. If the community can no longer effectively intervene in the event of for example a 51 % liveness attack, then risk mitigation in the form of the warning system discussed by Buterin may not be effective.

  8. The consensus mechanism has in this case through derivatives grown so large and interconnected that it has overloaded its ultimate arbitrator, the social consensus mechanism. It is a special and sort of inverted case of issues Buterin warned about.

If the deposit ratio grows very high, it is reasonable to argue that Ethereum becomes less secure. We can avert this by reducing issuance.

The switch to d from D will be done to preserve the same APR at the same proportion staked when Ethereum undergoes either deflation or inflation and follows analysis of Ethereum’s circulating supply equilibrium. It will not lower APR in the way you fear.


I will not have time to provide more answers going forward. I do find it desirable with an equilibrium staking yield above 1%, and also see this as the likely outcome from a change. But I also consider it a problem if the quantity of stake grows very large, which is why I think we should specify a lower issuance yield in this scenario, to stop the growth. This is a matter of trade-offs, where we must seek to balance many different priorities.

1 Like