Why enshrine Proposer-Builder Separation? A viable path to ePBS

Why enshrine Proposer-Builder Separation? A viable path to ePBS

by mike neuder and justin drake; may 25, 2023

tl;dr; Proposer-Builder Separation (PBS) decouples the task of block proposing (done by PoS validators) from block building (done most profitably by MEV searchers). PBS aims to improve access to MEV for validators by explicitly creating a permissionless market for block production. By allowing proposers to outsource block construction, validators can continue running on consumer-grade hardware without missing out on the valuable MEV exposed while they are the elected proposer. mev-boost implements out-of-protocol PBS and accounts for ≈90% of Ethereum blocks. Enshrined PBS (ePBS, sometimes referred to as in-protocol/IP PBS) evolves the consensus layer to implement PBS at the protocol level. While ePBS has been discussed since 2021 and is part of Ethereum’s roadmap, recent events (Low-Carb Crusador, Shapella mev-boost prysm signature bug, & relay response to unbundling) have turned the attention of the Ethereum community towards mev-boost and the evolution of PBS.

This document aims to

[a] outline arguments for ePBS (as opposed to continuing with mev-boost),
[b] present and respond to the counter-arguments to ePBS,
[c] describe desirable properties of ePBS mechanisms,
[d] sketch an ePBS design based on the existing research,
[e] highlight optimistic relaying as an additional tool to build towards ePBS, and
[f] encourage discussions around the ePBS design space.

This document does not aim to

[a] perform an exhaustive literature review (see here),
[b] fully spec out an ePBS implementation, or
[c] cover alternative designs for ePBS.

Many thanks to Barnabé, Dan Marzec, Terence, Chris Hager, Toni, Francesco, Rajiv, Thomas, and Jacob for comments on draft versions of this document.


Introduction

Proposer-Builder Separation (PBS) allows validators to outsource their block building duties to a set of specialized builders who are well equipped to extract MEV (hence separating the roles of proposer and builder). Proposers sell their block-production rights to builders who pay for the privilege of choosing the transaction ordering in a block. Proposers earn MEV rewards in addition to their protocol issuance, and block builders compete to assemble valuable blocks while saving a portion of the MEV for themselves as profit.

Enshrined PBS

Enshrined PBS (ePBS) advocates for implementing PBS into the consensus layer of the Ethereum protocol. Because there was no in-protocol solution at the time of the merge, Flashbots built mev-boost, which became a massively adopted out-of-protocol solution for PBS that accounts for ≈90% of Ethereum blocks produced.

Figure 1 – mev-boost slot share (orange) since the merge. Source mevboost.pics.

mev-boost continues to be critical infrastructure provided to grant permissionless access to the external block-building market for all validators, but it relies heavily on a small set of centralized relays to act as mutually-trusted auctioneers facilitating the block-production pipeline. We present the case for ePBS by highlighting (i) that relays are antithetical to Ethereum’s core values, (ii) the risks and inefficiences of side-car software, and (iii) the costs and unsustainability of relay operations.

Reasons to enshrine

  • Relays oppose Ethereum’s values. The following core tenants of Ethereum are eroded by the mass dependence on relays.
    • Decentralization: Relays are centralized. Six relays, operated by five different entities, account for 99% of mev-boost blocks. This small consortium of relay operators should not play such an outsized role in the ecosystem.
    • Censorship resistance: Relays can censor blocks. Since relays are centralized, they are exposed to regulation. This played out post-merge as some relays were pressured to censor transactions interacting with addresses on the OFAC sanctions list.
    • Trustlessness: Relays are trusted by validators and builders. Validators trust relays to provide them a valid block header and to publish the full beacon block; builders trust relays not to steal MEV. A violation of either of these trust assumptions would be detectable, but as demonstrated by the “Low-Carb Crusader”, dishonesty can be profitable, even if only through a one-time attack.
  • Out-of-protocol software is brittle.
    • The “Low-Carb Crusader” unbundling exploited a relay vulnerability for 20+ million USD. This attack and the general class of equivocation attacks it embodies demonstrate that relays are valuable targets outside of the protocol.
    • The relay response to the unbundling attack caused consensus instability. Due to relay-induced latency into the block-production pipeline, there was a 5x increase in reorged blocks immediately after the attack. See “Time, slots, and the ordering of events in Ethereum Proof-of-Stake” for more details.
    • During the Shapella upgrade, there was a bug in the Prysm code that interacts with mev-boost. This resulted in a brief 10x spike in missed slots immediately following the hard-fork. This bug was not caught because the code path for externally-built blocks is not covered by the consensus spec tests.
    • There are significant core-dev coordination costs involved in maintaining compatiblity between beacon clients & relays. Each hard-fork represents a significant amount of work from the relay and core developers to ensure mev-boost continues functioning. This involves designing the builder spec, maintaining/improving the relay spec, and the software changes on the beacon clients, mev-boost, and the mev-boost relays. Because mev-boost is out-of-protocol, this coordination is strictly additive to the standard ACD pipeline and usually happens later in the development cycle as a result.
    • mev-boost does not inherit the benefits of client diversity and the full consensus specification process. Though there are multiple relay repositories, the vast majority of blocks flow through relays using the flashbots implementation. While this is simpler to maintain, it lacks the structural benefits of client diversity enjoyed by the beacon nodes; the full specification/spec-test infrastructure is also not leveraged by the differing relay repositories.
  • Relays are expensive public goods.
    • Relay operational costs range from ≈20k-100k USD per-year depending on the desired performance. This doesn’t include engineering and DevOps costs associated with running a highly-available production service.
    • Relays are public goods that don’t have a clear funding model. While there are discussions around guilds, grants, and other funding vehicles, there is no obvious way to support relay development and operation (similar to the issues faced in supporting core-dev teams).

~~ ePBS resolves these issues by eliminating the relay. ~~

Note: MEV burn is currently being explored for its economic & security benefits. If we decide to pursue MEV burn, these benefits serve as yet another carrot on a stick for enshrinement.

Reasons not to enshrine

We believe it is important to highlight the counter-point of enshrinement by addressing the main arguments and presenting our responses.

  • "If it ain’t broke don’t fix it." mev-boost has worked incredibly well given the scale of its adoption. As the implementation continues to harden, we can gain confidence in its security properties and build out the specification. If we can find a credibly neutral way to fund a set of relays, then we could continue depending on them into the future.
    • Response – mev-boost has worked well, but there are no guarantees that this stability will continue. Another major censorship event, further attacks, and continued centralization pressures of relays, builders, and searchers pose significant risks to Ethereum. There is value in having clarity about ePBS to handle a situation where there is a pressing need for faster enshrinement. Additionally, ePBS will take time to design and implement – we should start formalizing it now, even if we continue with the relays for the next O(1-2 \; years) as ePBS progresses.
  • Could MEV be addressed with different tools? There is a growing discourse around protecting users from MEV on the application/transaction level. SUAVE, CoW swap, and MEVBlocker are three of many solutions that are continuing to gain usage. If a significant portion of MEV can be protected against, perhaps enshrining PBS is an unnecessary step on an already ambitious roadmap.
    • Response – We hope that this line of work can help protect users from “toxic” MEV, but we don’t expect on-chain MEV to ever be fully eliminated. Further, some MEV is extracted off-chain, requiring sophistication beyond just computational power. For example, in order to execute a CEX-DEX arbitrage, a validator would need liquidity and connectivity with a CEX in addition to the algorithmic resources to find and execute such an opportunity. We don’t envision a future in which there is little to no MEV in Ethereum or a solo-staking validator could meaningfully extract it on their own.
  • There are other roadmap items that should take precedence. The roadmap has many goals beyond ePBS. If we choose to go ahead with ePBS, it begs the question of where this can fit on the roadmap and what upgrades will be pushed down the line as a result.
    • Response – We believe that ePBS depends on Single-Slot Finality (SSF) for security and complexity reasons. Additionally, a validator set consolidation is a prerequisite for any SSF progress (see Increase the MAX_EFFECTIVE_BALANCE). The resource allocation problem is difficult, but we believe that ePBS should be part of these discussions, especially in the context of being bundled (pun-intended) with a larger consensus upgrade.
  • What is the right thing to enshrine? From a protocol design perspective, there are many mechanisms that could be implemented. BarnabĂ© explores these concepts in “Unbundling PBS”, “Notes on Proposer-Builder Separation”, and “Seeing like a protocol”. One takeaway from this work is that mev-boost implements a block-auction, which is not the only option for ePBS. Julian explores this further in “Block vs Slot Auction PBS”.
    • Response – ePBS is only useful insofar as it is adopted by builders and validators; the worst-case scenario is that ePBS is sidestepped by out-of-protocol solutions we didn’t foresee. While we acknowledge that any protocol upgrade has unknown-unknowns, we believe that by opening the discussion, working to achieve rough community consensus, and taking the next step in formalizing the design space of ePBS will improve confidence around what we are working towards. We also present the optimistic relay roadmap below, which takes a more iterative approach at evolving mev-boost.

ePBS design space

For extensive ePBS literature links see “Bookmarks relevent for Proposer-Builder Separation researchers”. We define the following properties as desirable:

  1. honest builder publication safety – If an honest builder wins the auction, the builder (i) must have an opportunity to create a block, and (ii) must be confident that any payload contents they release become canonical (i.e., protection from unbundling & equivocation attacks from the proposer).
  2. honest builder payment safety – If an honest builder payment is processed, the builder must be able to publish a block that becomes canonical.
  3. honest proposer safety – If an honest proposer commits to a block on-time, they must receive a payment at least as large as specified by the bid they selected.
  4. permissionless – Any builder can participate in the auction and any validator can outsource block production.
  5. censorship resistance – There must be a mechanism by which honest proposers can force through transactions they suspect are being censored without significantly sacrificing on their own rewards (“If we rely on altruism, don’t make altruism expensive” –Vitalik).
  6. roadmap compatibility – The design must be compatible with future roadmap upgrades (SSF, mev-burn, distributed block-building, SSLE, DAS, etc).

One design instantiation – Two-Block HeadLock (TBHL)

While there are many proposed ePBS implementations, we present a small modification of the original two-slot design from Vitalik. We call it Two-Block HeadLock (TBHL) because it uses a single slot to produce two blocks. The first is a proposer block that contains a commitment to a specific execution payload and the second is a builder block that contains the actual transaction contents (here we just call the overall pair of blocks a “single” slot because only one execution payload is produced). Note that with a second round of attestations, the slot time will likely need to increase. TBHL also incorporates some of the features of headlock to protect builders from proposer equivocations. TBHL shares many components with the current mechanism (HLMD-GHOST) and satisfies the six properties specified above.

Note: This is a sketch of the design; it is intentionally brief to improve readability. If we gain confidence that TBHL is a good overall approach, we can begin the specification and full security analysis. The aim is to present a simple, concrete example of a mechanism that satisfies the ePBS design properties, without overloading the reader with implementation details.

Figure 2 – The slot anatomy of TBHL. A proposer block is proposed and attested to in the purple phase, while a builder block is proposed and attested to in the yellow phase. The proposers, attesters, and builders each make different observations at various timestamps in the slot.

TBHL has the notion of proposer and builder blocks. Each slot can contain at most: one proposer block + one builder block, each of which receives attestations. The slot duration is divided into 4 periods.

t=t_0 : The proposer chooses winning bid and publishes a proposer block. The proposer starts by observing the bidpool, which is a p2p topic where builders send their bids. The proposer selects one of these bids and includes it in a block they publish before t_1.
t=t_1 : The attesting committee for the proposer block observes for a timely proposal. This is the equivalent of the “attestation deadline” at t=4 in the current mechanism. If at least one block is seen, the attesting committee votes for the first one that they saw. If no block is observed, the attesting committee votes for an empty slot (this requires block, slot voting).
t=t_{1.5} : The attesting committee for the builder block checks for equivocations. If the attesting committee sees (i) more than one proposer block or (ii) no proposer blocks, they give no proposer boost to any subsequent builder block. If the attesting committee sees a unique proposer block, they give proposer boost to the builder associated with that bid (see “Headlock in ePBS” for more details).
t=t_2 : The builder checks if they are the unique winner. If a builder sees an equivocation, they produce a block that includes the equivocation as proof that their unconditional payment should be reverted. Otherwise, the builder can safely publish their builder block with a payload (the transaction contents). If the builder does not see the proposer block as the head of the chain, they publish an empty block extending their head (see “Headlock in ePBS” for more details).
t=t_3 : The attesting committee for the builder block observes for a timely proposal. This is a round of attestations that vote for the builder block. This makes t_3 a second attestation deadline.

We can assert that this mechanism satisfies the ePBS design properties.

  1. honest builder publication safety – The only situation where builder safety could be in question is if the proposer equivocates. For brevity, the details of the equivocation protection are left out of this document. Please see “Headlock in ePBS”.
  2. honest builder payment safety – If an honest builder is selected and their payment is processed, they will either (i) see no equivocations and have the opportunity to create a block with confidence that they are the unique recipient of proposer boost or (ii) see an equivocation and use it as proof to revert the payment. Again, please see “Headlock in ePBS” for further details.
  3. honest proposer safety – If an honest proposer commits to a block on-time, their block will receive attestations and the unconditional payment will go through without reversion because the builder will not have any proof of an equivocation. Even if the builder block is not produced, the bid payment occurs so long as no equivocation proof is presented.
  4. permissionless – The p2p layer is permissionless and any builder can submit bids to the bidpool. Any validator can listen to the bidpool if they want to outsource block building, or they can choose to build locally instead.
  5. censorship resistance – The proposal is compatible with censorship resistance schemes. For example, the proposer block could contain a forward inclusion list. See “PBS censorship-resistance alternatives” for more context.
  6. roadmap compatiblity – SSF fits naturally with this proposal by adding a third round of attestations after the builder block attestation round. The third round includes the full validator set and justifies the block immediately with a supermajority consensus. See “A simple Single Slot Finality protocol” for more details. This mechanism is also highly compatible with mev-burn, as the base fee floor deadline, D, could precede t_0.

Optimistic relaying – an iterative approach to PBS

The design framework and TBHL presented above provide a “top-down” approach to ePBS. This has historically been the way R&D is done in Ethereum. Once the design is fleshed out, a spec is written, and the client teams implement it.

The existence of mev-boost and in particular mev-boost relays gives us an interesting additional angle to approach the problem – “bottom-up”. We can imagine there are many PBS implementations that lie on a spectrum between the original mev-boost implementation and full ePBS. By modifying the relay, we can move “up” towards an ePBS implementation without needing to modify the spec and make changes to the consensus node software. This allows us to forerun and derisk some of the features of a full ePBS system (e.g., are builders OK with us removing cancellations?) while also remaining agile. This objective has already been presented in the optimistic roadmap.

The main theme of the optimistic roadmap is to remove relay responsibilities. This has the added benefit of improving the operational efficiency of running a relay. As mentioned in “Reasons to enshrine,” relay operation is expensive and is currently being done only as a public good. By lowering the barrier to entry for relay operaters, we enable a more sustainable future for mev-boost as we flesh out the details of ePBS.

Block submission in mev-boost

Before describing optimistic relaying, we briefly present the builder bid submission pipeline in the mev-boost-relay. Processing builder bids is the main function of the relay, and incurs the highest latency and compute costs. When a builder submits a bid to the relay the following occurs.

Figure 3 – Once the builder block is received by the relay, it is validated against an execution layer (EL) client. Once it is validated, the block is eligible to win the auction and may be signed by the proposer. Once the relay receives the signed header, it publishes the block to the p2p through a consensus layer (CL) client.

Since hundreds of bids are submitted each slot, the relay must (i) handle the ingress bytes of all the builder submissions, (ii) simulate the blocks on the EL clients, and (iii) serve as a data availablity layer for the execution payloads. Additionally, the validator relies on the relay to publish the block in a timely manner once they sign the header.

Optimistic relaying v1

The first version of optimistic relaying simply removes the block validation step from the block submission pipeline.

Figure 4 – Once the builder block is received by the relay, it is immediately eligible to win the auction and be signed by the proposer. Once the relay receives the signed header, it publishes the block to the p2p network through a consensus layer (CL) client.

The risk incurred by skipping the block validation is that an invalid block may be unknownly signed by the validator. This results in a missed slot because the attesting committee will reject the invalid block. The relay financially protects the validator against this situation by holding builder collateral. If a bad builder block results in a proposer missing a slot, the relay uses the builder collateral to refund the proposer. Optimistic relaying v1 is already upstreamed into the Flashbot’s mev-boost-relay repository and running on ultra sound relay. See “An optimistic weekend” and “Optimistic relays and where to find them” for more details.

Optimistic relaying endgame

The final iteration of optimistic relaying behaves more like TBHL. Instead of the attesting committee enforcing the rules, the relay serves as a centralized “oracle” for the timeliness of events that take place in the bidpool. The flow of a block proposal is diagrammed below.

Figure 5 – Builders now directly submit bids to the p2p layer (instead of the relay). Proposers observe these bids and sign the corresponding header of the winning bid. The builder of that signed header publishes the full block. The relay observes the bidpool and checks for timeliness of (i) the proposer’s signed header and (ii) the builder’s block publication. Notice that these observations are exactly what the attesting committee is responsible for in TBHL. The relay still holds builder collateral to refund a proposer if they sign a header on-time, but the builder doesn’t produce a valid block.

Endgame optimistic relaying contains some of the ePBS machinery; proposers and builders will be interacting directly through the bidpool and relays will be implementing the validity conditions that the attesting committee would enforce at the consensus layer. Additionally, relay operation at that point is reduced to a collateralized mempool oracle service, which should be much cheaper and easier to run than the full validating relays of today.

Conclusion

Proposer-Builder Separation is an important piece of Ethereum’s roadmap and continues to gain momentum in the public discourse. This document aims to present the arguments for and against enshrinement, lay out design goals of an ePBS mechanism, present Two-Block HeadLock (a minor variant of Two-slot PBS), and describe the utility of the optimistic relay roadmap. We hope to open up the enshrinement discussion and solicit alternative ePBS proposals from the community. While these “top-down” design and specification discussions continue, we hope to move forward on the “bottom-up” approach of optimistic relaying with the goal of making relays cheaper and more sustainable in the medium-term.

For any questions, concerns, or corrections, please don’t hesitate to reach out on twitter or through telegram.

thanks for reading!
-mike & justin

31 Likes

Can you elaborate on this?


From my perspective, SSF helps ePBS achieve a better honest builder payment safety property: if the auction-winning builder is honest, then that builder’s block must become canonical. In fact, an SSF protocol can quickly (i) identify the auction-winning builder from the proposer’s messages (potentially multiple equivocations), and (ii) finalize the auction-winning builder’s block. We cannot achieve a property this strong without SSF because all blocks must go through a long unfinalized period, during which they bear the risk of getting reorged.

This is exactly the next question we need to answer. We (mostly @fradmt) are writing a piece making this case. The high-level argument is that proposer boost was introduced into HLMD-GHOST to provide some protection against ex-post reorgs and balancing attacks. Proposer boost is effective because honest proposers will resolve the chain split with a timely block that automatically gets 40% attestation weight. Intuitively, TBHL as described above makes it so every other block is a builder block. This results in situations where an attacker controlling 2 consecutive slots now controls 4 slots in a row effectively. There is a more formal case to be made, but intuitively, the security properties of HLMD-GHOST with proposer boost are not super well understood, and adding in every-other block being malicious by definition makes those security properties worse.

Again, I see this as the most important next question to answer :slight_smile:

Very interesting read. I’m wondering, how do you see the current relay landscape evolving into the optimistic relaying endgame approach? In terms of adoption, I’m hesitant all relays will adopt this model. If they do would the centralized relay “oracle” be in fact just one relay/entity or a committee of them with some sort of majority rule?

2 Likes

Hi Alvaro :slight_smile:

From a redundancy and safety perspective it would be amazing if we got everyone to agree to do this and form a committee based oracle as you describe. But that is probably pretty difficult to coordinate as you mention.

I think the likely medium-term solution is that some subset of relays run optimistic mode where they are just a proxy between the builder and the proposer. In other words, the builder just forwards their bids through the relay, and the proposer still uses direct connection with the relay. The relay verifies that the builder has sufficient collateral, but never receives the block contents. When the proposer returns the signed header to the relay, the relay sends a request to the builder to publish from their end. So this adds one extra relay->builder round of network latency, but the relay never has to download all the bytes coming from the various builders.

There is actually a competitive advantage for relays to run like this, because builder bids are activated immediately (within a few ms, where now it takes ~20-1000ms), so the critical late-slot bids will be active immediately. Additionally, its way cheaper to run a relay in this mode. I could see a world where this becomes the dominant relay strategy.

But would love to hear any other ideas you have :slight_smile:

2 Likes

Why do the 2 blocks need to be “real” blocks? Couldn’t we simply have them be two components of the same slot (with an extended duration)? Is this to ensure we get a different committee for each half?

5 Likes

Great post! Quite a general question, but to what extent are proposers needed at all in PBS designs? It seems their job is relegated to simply selecting the winning bid. Couldn’t the attesting committee do this?

This is a great question, Tim! Phil Daian brought this exact same thing up when we presented it to him. I agree that this probably makes the most sense. We present them as two different blocks because i think it is intuitively easier to highlight the fork-choice rule being applied to the proposer block after the first round of attestations to determine who the builder. But yes, from a spec/implementation perspective, there seems to be room to simplify :slight_smile:

3 Likes

i think proposers are always necessary. The simplest reason is that if someone wants to build a block locally and not use the external block building market, they should be able to without penalty (i.e., we don’t want to ~force~ people to use ePBS). Another reason is for censorship resistance. IIUC these designs rely on having an honest proposer specify a set of txns that must be included. Without the proposer, the builders have no constraints placed on them.

2 Likes

I agree, I would even say optimistic relays are currently the dominant relay strategy. The issue I see though is that by basing its dominance on latency, what incentive is there to switch to a p2p based model (from a validator and builder both with a profit maximising perspective)? Wouldn’t the p2p be slower and potentially less profitable? I guess if all relays switch to a p2p model and there’s no alternative

3 Likes

Proposers being able to build a block locally is not necessarily a property that will always hold true, for example it wouldn’t in ePBS with smoothing or burning or anyway what is sometimes referred to as “consensus bids”. Censorship resistance can also be decoupled from choosing the winning bid, for example by having forward inclusion list proposers that are separate from the actual proposers.

Imho, the main reason why proposers are necessary is simply that our consensus protocol doesn’t work without the coordination provided by proposers. We can have very nice provable security properties for LMD-GHOST-like protocols, but they entirely depend on this coordination. If you were to just have attesters vote without it, the protocol becomes extremely vulnerable to balancing attacks.

Also, choosing the winning bid is not the only responsibility of proposers. They also make the beacon block part (including attestations, deposits, withdrawals etc
), and you don’t really want to auction that off.

3 Likes

Quite an interesting topic.

However, I’m curious, why do we still need the “relay” at the Optimistic Relaying Endgame stage? If the relays are only used for staking collaterals and slashing dishonest builders, wouldn’t there be a more efficient and decentralized way (perhaps the proposer could verify whether the block is published after signing the block header) to achieve this?

Is it not plausible that over time builder competition will drive out most of the builders that are less effective/efficient?

Imaging a scenario where:

  • Proposers no longer have the ability to build block locally
  • All blocks in the network are built by 5 builders (among them 2 builders build 80% of the blocks)
  • Nation state actors then capture all 5 builders through a combination of bribes and threats
  • All 5 builders start to censor transactions (by submitting bids that ignore the inclusion list)

What do the validators do in such cases?

  • do they accept the highest censoring bid that to prevent the chain from halting?
  • do they reject all censoring bids and vote for empty blocks until another non-captured builder eventually joins back in?

I have to agree with @mikeneuder that proposers should always have the options to build a block locally even if features like inclusion list are already implemented

2 Likes

Great post for comprehensive analysis of PBS and its potential enshrinement within the Ethereum protocol as ePBS!

In particular, the bottom-up approach, which involves leveraging existing PBS infrastructure (relays), to be especially intriguing. This strategy could yield significant benefits in terms of efficiency and scalability.

further questions on implementing the optimistic roadmap

  1. As we move towards phase 1 (Asynchronous block validation) of the roadmap, what viable options exist or could be developed for existing relays/teams interested in running new relays? Additionally, are there any community tools or resources that could facilitate this transition and ensure a smooth implementation process?

  2. Roadmap prioritization and community involvement: Considering the numerous upgrades planned for the Ethereum ecosystem and various teams working on the PBS front, how can the Ethereum community, including developers, stakeholders, and users, actively participate in these decision-making processes to ensure the most effective and efficient path forward?

1 Like

ya its a good point! it is for sure not clear that a user would prefer the p2p version over the last iteration that still has relays as a proxy for the bids. one argument to switch to the p2p is if it turns out to be just faster than the relay proxy version. for example, if builders are well connected and validators hear about their bids faster than routing through a relay. i think more likely is the most competitive relays serve as a high-speed bid proxy.

Do you have any in mind? we have thought about trying to make it a smart contract or similar, but the issue we usually run into is that we need some source of truth about the timing of events that happened. e.g., we need to know that the proposer signed the header “on-time” and that the builder produced the full block “on-time”. This is why we call it a “mempool oracle service”, because the relay serves as the source of truth. would love to hear any other ideas you have though!

1 Like

IMO this is one of the biggest concerns I have with MEV burn. it really removes the ability for a validator to build locally, unless they are willing to burn the amount of ETH required by the floor bid. I really like the idea of the validator being able to build locally, but that is also not compatible with stateless validators, so maybe its just not feasible in the endgame version of the protocol.

1 Like
  1. we already have phase 1 implemented and running on ultra sound relay! the code is upstreamed into the flashbots repo and open source for anyone to use if they like. there have been some discussions around encouraging funding for non-censoring relays, but besides that there is not much financial support for new entrants. that being said, we are super willing to help any new relay operators get set up with optimistic relaying in terms of running the code and providing infrastructure details. as we move towards the latter phases of the roadmap, we think the barrier of entry will continue to shrink.

  2. this is a great question and also something that the EF is thinking hard about. i think it will grow organically beyond the small group of folks thinking about it currently to eventually having an EIP, community calls, open problems etc. that all feels a bit premature at the moment given we are still fleshing out the designs and thinking about big picture. this post aimed at providing a snapshot into the current discussions and we hope that in the next few months we can coalesce behind a specific design (this is a longer-term project just because of how significantly it may change the “shape” of the consensus layer). i would love to chat if you have any other ideas about how to get more community engagement :slight_smile:

1 Like

Without the ability to propose blocks, what are validators? Mere voters? We all know how well our so-called democratic political systems works. When all the candidates are terrible, what’s the point of having hundreds of millions of voters, if they have almost no power? All we can do is to vote for what perceives to be the “lesser of evils” and suffer the equally bad consequences.

The ability to propose block locally, imho, is the last defense (without resorting to the social layer) against attacks that target the block building infrastructure. I have no doubt that ePBS would centralize the block builders. Therefore it is crucial to preserve validators’ option to build blocks in a decentralized fashion, even if such option is almost never exercised in a normal scenario.

The mere existence of such option should suffice to deter attackers to not even bother trying to capture the builders in the first place

2 Likes

As Mike already mentioned, there’s a future where home-staking gets a lot easier through stateless validation, but where these low-resource validators are not able to build locally. Also there’s a future in which Danksharding makes local block building completely infeasible even for a validator with the equivalent of today’s resource requirements.

Still, it is in theory always possible to let at least well-resourced validators (e.g. staking pools) build their own blocks if they so desire, but it would be incompatible with ePBS designs with consensus bids (e.g. with smoothing or burning). I am not really sure that preserving this property has a lot of advantages, compared to what can be achieved with censorship resistance schemes.

2 Likes